LSIRD NAPLIO CONFERENCE PAPERS
The support to livestock producton in less-favoured areas
under the Common Agricultural Policy of the European Union
Eduardo Díez Patier & Daniel Trueba Herranz
Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food, Madrid, SPAIN
1. Background
The Community agricultural structures and rural development policy,
in general, and the attention paid to less-favoured agricultural areas,
in particular, are two subjects the responsible authorities for the Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP), throughout its history, cannot really be pleased
about.
It can even be said that one of the reasons for the classical CAP crisis
has been the difference in speed that, since the beginning, the EAGGF-Guarantee
Section and the EAGGF-Guidance Section, as well as their corresponding
action frameworks, markets and structures, have kept. It must not be forgotten
that at the Stresa Conference a resource distribution of 2/3 for markets
and 1/3 for structures was agreed though it was never observed. Till the
modification of the Structural Funds in 1988, the distribution was 95%
for the EAGGF-Guarantee Section and 5% for the EAGGF-Guidance Section,
approximately.
Not only was it a matter of different speeds. The requirement of national
cofinancing for structural and territorial measures, but not for market
measures, has meant a curb to agricultural holding modernization in those
Member States having greater economic difficulties which, besides, are,
in general, those with the largest number of less-favoured agricultural
areas.
Therefore, less-efficient agricultural holdings had larger difficulties
to get into the path leading to structural improvements, although they
were taken into account in the income policy when fixing the minimum guaranteed
prices, either influencing their increase or avoiding their reduction.
That implied a stimulus for the production increase in the most efficient
agricultural holdings which, without the need for following market signals,
gave rise to surpluses of costly financing.
In short, the CAP was, at first, subordinated to the market policy, leaving
structural subjects in the hands of national policies and reserving for
the Community just the cofinancing of particular projects.
2. Development
The adoption of the first real structural measures coincides with the
emergence of agricultural and livestock products surpluses. It followed
the Mansholt Memorandum of 1968 as well as its corresponding Plan which
was never applied in an integral, coherent way. It was the three socio-structural
Directive-package approved in 1972 on the modernization of farms, cessation
of farming and guidance and occupational training of farmers (Directives
72/159, 72/160 and 72/165).
However, it will not be till 1975 that the approval of rules of territorial
scope took place. Directive 75/268, on mountain and hill farming and farming
in certain less-favoured areas established detailed rules for the application
of paragraph 2, point 2, Article 39 of the Treaty of Rome on structural
and natural inequalities of the different agricultural regions and in fact
it is the first Community rule which allows differentiated treatments according
to natural conditions. Besides, it does so trough direct aids to farmers'incomes
by Compensatory Payments (CP).
This first package of rules was completed, in 1977 and 1978, through Regulations
on common measures to improve the conditions under which agricultural products
are processed and marketed and on aids to agricultural producer groups
and associations thereof (Regulations 355/77 and 1360/78, respectively).
A second generation of socio-structural provisions appeared in the late
eighties, and on the one hand coincided with the serious crisis of the
market policy which would give rise to the 1992 CAP Reform and, on the
other, with the modification of the Structural Funds and the new regional
policy in the Community resulting from the European Single Act.
The Directive on modernization of farms was totally amended, turning into
a Regulation on improving the efficiency of agricultural structures (Regulation
797/1985); the first environmental measures along with certain integral
and regional schemes (Mediterranean Integrated Programmes, less-favoured
areas schemes) were adopted; likewise, accompanying measures concerning
the agrobudgetary stabilisers prereform (set aside, reconversion and extensification,
advanced cessation, programme of agricultural income aids etc) were approved.
But, to the purpose of this paper, it is specially interested to underline
the new orientation of the Structural Funds which are designed around five
great objectives (in fact six, since the fifth one is divided into two),
three of which have territorial nature and two of those three are specifically
rural and agricultural. Such Funds are applied through Operational Schemes
of a territorial basis to the purpose of the distribution key of financial
resources as well as to the purpose of the range of possibilities to be
developed and financed. The overlap of horizontal measures (improvement
of structures) and those of territorial nature is generally solved through
both more flexible conditions in less-favoured areas and a larger percentage
of Community financing.
The asumption by the EAGGF-Guarantee Section of some kind of structural
action or reference to less-favoured areas would not appear till Commissioner
Mac Sharry's procedures for "support to the rural world", in
1990 and 1991, to favour small farmers or those located in less-favoured
areas. The 1992 CAP Reform will also finance its acompanying measures (afforestation,
advanced cessation and environmental measures) through the EAGGF-Guarantee
Section, although they have direct repercussion on specific territorial
bases or on livestock production.
3. Identification of less-favoured areas
As a result of the above mentioned, the first question arising is the
identification of less-favoured areas in the Community legislation. To
that end it can be considered:
a) Mountain, and less-favoured areas, in the sense of Directive
75/268. They are regions (made up of municipality groupings, NUTS IV) with
considerable problems to maintain the population or to preserve the natural
environment. There are several groups:
- Mountain areas with problems regarding altitude or slope gradient, which
means considerable difficulties for the development of farming (paragraph
3, Article 3 of the Directive).
- Areas with risk of depopulation, little productivity of the land and
low population density or even a trend to population regression (paragraph
3, Article 3 of the Directive).
- Other areas having specific limitations, that Member States can apply
for up to a maximum 4% of the Useful Arable Land (UAA), if need be to maintain
farming on (paragraph 5, Article 3 of the Directive).
b) Objective 1 Areas, in the sense of Regulation 2052/88, in which
the aim is the development and structural adjustment of the less developed
areas. The regions are defined in terms of NUTS II, when Gross National
Product (GNP) per capita is below 75% of the Community average, expressed
in the three-year average. Such a parameter can be obviated for the overperipheric
territories of France, Spain and Portugal, in Northern Ireland as well
as in the New Landers of the Federal Republic of Germany, (and also for
the new objective 6 created for Sweden and Finland as a consequence of
the last enlargement). Exceptionally, other adjoining territories can be
included in some regions where the level is lower than NUTS II and have
problems related to the GNP.
c) Objective 5b Areas, in the sense of Regulation 2052/88, in which
the aim is the promotion of rural development, making easier both the development
and the structural adjustment of the rural areas. Such areas are not included
in Objective 1, although they face, at municipality level (NUTS IV), agricultural
unemployment problems, low agricultural income level, low population density,
or other problems derived from the agricultural holding structure, ageing
of the agricultural population, pressure on the environment and the rural
space or specific location.
4. Aids to livestock production
4.1. Compensatory payments
In Directive 75/268 a Compensatory Payment (CP) for livestock head
(also for area unit) is established to be granted, in mountain and less-favoured
areas, to agricultural holding owners on active who commit themselves to
stay in the farm at least five years and have a minimum area of four hectares
(three hectares when it comes to Southern areas of the Community).
The aid is granted for the equivalent to Large Animal Unit (LAU) of cattle,
sheep, goats and horses. Dairy cows are only taken into consideration when
milk production is an important component in the farm production, and it
is restricted to 20 units when it refers to less-favoured areas included
in paragraphs 4 and 5, Article 3 of the Directive. In any case, the CP
is subject to the disposal of a territorial base equivalent to a 1,4 LAU/Ha
density.
The amount of the aid cannot be lower than 20,3 ECU/LAU or higher than
150 ECU/LAU, or, in exceptional cases, higher that 180 ECU/LAU. Within
this range, Member States can both adjust the amount of the CP, theoretically,
taking into account the seriousness of the permanent natural limitations
affecting farming, and establish complementary or restrictive conditions,
in particular when it comes to using practices compatible with both environmental
protection and natural space preservation.
The maximum eligible amount at the expense of the EAGGF-Guidance Section
is limited to the equivalent to 120 LAU per agricultural holding and, besides,
from 60 LAU on per holding, the maximum eligible amount per LAU is cut
down to 50% of the maximum amount of the CP provided for in general.
The Community cofinancing of the CP varies between 25% and 75%. As a rule
25% is applied; certain areas provided for in paragraph 3, Article 26 of
Regulation 797/85 have the right to obtain 50%, and mountain and less-favoured
areas, which besides are in Objective 1 areas, are entitled to obtain 70%.
Some comments can be made on this aid and they would be related to the
core of the matter which will be treated further ahead. The "diversity"
of the Community agriculture, that of its less-favoured areas together
with that of the characteristics of natural difficulties it has to face
is, by all means, important. In any case, it may not be so important as
to justify a range from 20,3 to 180 ECU por LAU which could affect the
conditions of competence provided for in Articles 92 y 93 of the Treaty.
But the debate diversity versus competence is inserted in that of "financial
solidarity": the demand of a minimum 30% of national cofinancing involves,
in some Member States, a real curb to establish a CP level next to the
maximum authorized limits, whereas other Member States enjoying more financial
resources can be more generous regarding this matter. This way, the CP
level is set up depending no so much on the specific difficulties of the
less-favoured areas but on the Member States resource availability.
4.2 Sheep supplementary premium
It is the most important measure of those included in "support
to the rural world" introduced by Commissioner Mac Sharry.
As it is well known, the basic element of the Common Organization of the
Market (COM) in sheep is a production premium based on the difference throughout
the year between the market price and the institutional base price. This
difference is later transformed into a premium per ewe and goat head. Ewes
which are not milked, and produce "heavy" lambs, get the whole
premium, whereas both ewes which are milked, and produce "light"
lambs, and goats get 80% of the premium. At present, the right to the premium
is subject to the individual quota scheme regime, based on the premium
received in the reference year 1991.
The suplementary premium is granted to sheep and goats located in the less-favoured
areas envisaged in Directive 75/268, and its present amount is 6.641 ECU
per head for ewes producing "heavy" lambs and 4.586 ECU for ewes
producing "light" lambs and goats, and it is wholly paid by the
EAGGF-Guarantee Section. As a reference, it can be pointed out that the
amount of the general premium for 1995 has been 24.82 ECU for ewes which
produce "heavy" lambs and 19.857 ECU for ewes which produce "light"
lambs and for goats. From the EAGGF-Guarantee Section budget, for 1995
financial year, 423.1 million ECU were paid as supplementary premium while
payments for the general premium reached 1,781.9 million ECU.
The financial solidarity (there is no cofinancing) of the EAGGF-Guarantee
Section makes every farmer get the specific premium if he is entitled to
it for being in less-favoured areas. Another conclusion of the analysis
of the amount paid, is that in most of the producing countries, sheep holdings
are located in these less-favoured areas (such as in Greece, Spain, France,
Portugal, Ireland and Austria). There is no risk of competence distortion
since, besides, the premium is the same for every producer.
4.3 Suckler cow supplementary premium
In the COM in beef as a consequece of the CAP reform, a suckler cow
premium relatively important, of 144.9 ECU/suckler cow (which is not milked),
is granted provided that a minimum livestock number is respected (2 LAU/Ha
in 1996) and within an individual quota scheme of the premium rights. Additionally,
there is an extensification premium to be referred to further ahead.
Besides, Member States are authorized to grant an additional premium up
to 30.19 ECU/cow, of which 24.15 ECU/cow are financed by EAGGF-Guarantee
Section in Objective 1 areas.
Such an approach tries to avoid the appearance of competence problems in
each Member State, but it does so by dint of the financial solidarity principle
characteristic of the EAGGF-Guarantee Section, since the supplementary
premiums for suckler cows which are not in Objective 1 areas must be financed
by national budgets, as it happens when it comes to paying the possible
excess up to 30.19 ECU/cow of those in Objective 1 areas. In practice,
only Member States with a high percentage of suckler cows in Objective
1 areas are interested in applying this supplementary premium and obviously
they will probably do it only to the limit of 24.15 ECU/cow of the Community
financing.
4.4. Other aids in the COM framework
a) In the COM in beef, the suckler cow premium and the young animal
special premium both have an extensification complement when the density
factor is lower than 1.4LAU/Ha. For 1996, the amount of such an extensification
premium is 36.23 ECU/LAU. As a reference, the ordinary premium for suckler
cow is 144.90 ECU/cow and the special young animal premium is 108.70 ECU/head.
Even recently the Council of Ministers of the E.U. has approved a second
level of the extensification premium for livestock numbers under 1 LAU/Ha.
The total extensification premium amount in the financial year 1995 of
the EAGGF-Guarantee Section was 438.1 million ECU.
These extensification premiums are not specifically linked to less-favoured
areas recognised by the Community, as defined in previous points in this
paper, but undoubtedly such areas generally fulfil the ideal conditions
for extensive livestock and that is why they are those which most benefit
from these aids. For example, in Spain and in Greece the extensification
premiums represent about 20% of the whole set of the beef sector premiums,
whereas for the Community as a whole such a figure is 10% (data from EAGGF-Guidance
Section, 1995 financial year).
b) Regarding aids subject to individual quota schemes (special sheep premium
and special suckler cow premium) the Community regulation allows Member
States to define certain sensitive areas from which quota transfer to other
areas is not permitted. Needles to say that such a restriction is provided
to protect less-favoured areas producers, but due to the way the authorization
has been introduced Member States have difficulties in using it owing to
matters of interference with the general quota market and, probably, to
domestic policy problems.
c) Till the CAP reform and the establishement of the individual quota scheme
for the payment of the sheep sector premium, there used to be a limit of
500 heads per farm, and from that limit on producers were paid 50% of the
premium, though in respect of less-favoured areas such a limit was 1000
heads for herd. Taking into account the individual quota scheme and to
avoid artificial division of herds, such limits were removed after the
1992 reform and along whith the evidence of an action to favour livestock
in less-favoured areas.
d) Among the acompanying measures of the CAP reform, that of environmental
nature (Regulation 2078/92) could have been a good support to livestock
in less-favoured areas. Nevertheless, the fact that, although such measures
are financed by the EAGGF-Guarantee Section, a national confinancing is
requested (and even though in Objective 1 areas such national cofinancing
is 25% versus 50% in other areas), once again makes more difficult its
implementation by countries with scarce resources. As an example, Germany,
Finland and France together catch in between 60% and 65% of the resources
spent by the EAGGF-Guarantee Section, even though their Objective 1 areas
represent just 20% of the total.
Besides, it is likely that in the conception and development of this Regulation,
environmental criteria of Northern countries have been imposed, and such
countries are far from aridity, drought and desertification problems the
less-favoured areas in Southern countries have to face. To confirm all
this it can be pointed out that to have access to the aids envisaged in
this Regulation regarding livestock activity a reduction in the
livestock number per hectare is required -Article 2.c-, whereas in many
less-favoured areas there is plenty of forage area, although not very productive,
and the problem is tokeep both the herd and the economic
activity.
4.5. Aids to improve the efficiency of farms and Operational Programmes
In general, aids to improve agricultural and livestock holdings are
regulated by Regulation 2328/91, on improving the efficiency of the agricultural
structures. Such aids are part of Objective 5a of the Structural Funds,
although they also have a territorial distribution to the purpose of the
partition of the Funds as a whole. The main characteristics of such an
aid scheme are as follows:
- The holder must practise farming as the main activity, with some flexibility
and the holding must have an income per agricultural labour unit under
120% of a reference income of the correponding region. Granting of aids
to producers associations is foreseen with some limitations.
- The farmer professional training must be documented. He must commit himself
to keeping a minimum record of the holding accounts and it is necessary
to submit an Improvement Plan where objectives to be reached and measures
to be taken to his purpose must be described.
- Livestock productions have several limitations (milk, beef cattle, pig
meat, eggs and poultry) which, in general, can only made more flexible
when taking into consideration both environmental matters and animal welfare,
but bearing in mind the limitation of the production potential.
- There are ceilings established for investments to be made, referred to
the holding as a whole and to the agricultural labour unit it bears.
- The aids, in subsidy form, are limited to 20% (and 35% for buildings)
in general, but both in mountain and less-favoured areas envisaged in Directive
75/268 such figures raise up to 30% y 45%.
- The Community cofinancing of EAGGF-Guidance Section varies between 25%
and 50%, in general and between 50% and 75% in Objective 1 areas and, in
the latter, the Community cofinancing can exceptionally reach 80% in countries
benefiting from the Cohesion Fund (Spain, Portugal, Greece and Ireland)
and 85% in overperipheric regions and in Greek peripheric islands. This
financing scheme also applies to the Operational Programmes of the Objective
1 and 5b regions of the Structural Funds.
Regulation 2328/91 contitutes, besides, the criteria and detailed rules
for Articles 92 and 93 of the Treaty regarding national aids to agricultural
holdings. Under particular conditions national aids to agricultural holdings
are strictly forbidden and, in other cases, the amount of such aids is
limited.
All which has been stated in the previous paragraph has meant, besides,
a curb to the possibility for Member States to include, in the Operational
Programmes of Objective 1 and 5b areas real specific plans for livestock
development in less-favoured areas, which should be adapted to the problems
and needs of each region although the latter do not meet the general rules
of Regulation 2328/91.
This way, the Operational Programmes in Objective 1 and 5b areas, contrary
to the initial approach, do not constitute an appropriate reference framework
for private investments in agricultural and livestock productive sectors
and they are limited to cofinance national or local administration actions.
It is true that in the Operational Programmes several collective actions
(genetic, health, hygenic-sanitary conditions of production improvements)
for herd development in less-favoured areas have place, but they are just
secondary measures regarding the main goal which is to make livestock holdings
viable.
In short, and bearing in mind the experience of some Southern Community
Member States which have considerable problems concerning livestock development
in less-favoured areas, it can be stated that the Community Support Framework
is not an adequate answer to the existing problems.
5. Considerations for the future
In January, 1995, Italy submitted a memorandum on mountain and hill
agriculture which gave rise to several debates within the Council which
proved the existence of a real problem as well as the inadequacy of the
present measures to solve it. Due to the reservations of some Member States
along with that of the Commission, no steps ahead could be taken. Such
Member States were worried about both the budgetary repercussions and the
competence distortion problems which could derive from some of the aids
Italy asked for.
Nevertheless, the outcome of the Cork Conference recently held (November,
1996) on rural development is still more worrying. It is so, not only because
no specific reference to less-favoured areas was made on the Final Declaration,
but because most of the ideas envisaged in it (diversity, subsidiarity,
diversification, cofinancing, reduction in the importance of the market
policy and so on) could have counterproductive effects on the agricultural
and livestock development in less-favoured areas.
In the Community agriculture as a whole, and in particular in less-favoured
areas, there will be neither farmers nor rural world to be developed if
there is not an adequate agricultural activity considered in its most economic,
dinamic, competitive sense.
Such an activity will undoubtedly need certain aids to compete on open
markets, and the former could be more or less directly granted or as compensation
for the occupation and maintenance of the territory as well as to make
easier both habitability and development in the rural world. But, it must
be stressed that the priority is to maintain and ensure an agricultural
and livestock production activity with economic and market foundations.
On the other hand, it is also certain that the granting of certain specific
aids in less-favoured areas could bring about risks of competence distorsion,
but it is considered there are other alternatives to maintain agricultural
and livestock activity if the problem is approched from the Cohesion spirit
set up in the Treatry after Maastricht and, as stated in Article 130 B,
such spirit must be the reference when it comes to approaching and developing
all the Community policies, including the CAP.
From this Cohesion prospect, an approach to the problem solution about
agricultural and livestock development in less-favoured areas could be
as follows:
a) Compensatory Payments should be unified at an adequate intermediate
level, enlarging the maximum eligible and being totally financed by the
EAGGF. This will perhaps require a revision of the present definition of
areas.
b) A Community reserve of quotas for less-favoured areas should be available
(milk, premium to ewes, premium to suckler cows) and granted to farmers
(individuals o enterprises) who settled or enlarged their activity in such
areas. It goes without saying that such reserve quotas could not be transferred
to an area different from that they had been allocated to.
c) Regarding aids to investments in agricultural holdings located in less-favoured
areas, most of the specific restrictions imposed on the livestock activity
should be removed and lots of other general requirements (full-time farmers,
maximum limit of investment, etc) should be made more flexible or even
removed.
d) "Rural world support" measures should be kept and encouraged,
and the allocation of certain aids to the less-favoured areas within the
COM framework, being financed by the EAGGF-Guarantee Section, should proceed.
e) Diversification and support activities (rural tourism, payments for
environmental measures, provision of services, etc) and in general everything
known as sustainable rural development must obviously be kept and encouraged
as a complement to the agriculture and livestock activity although it is
sure that such measures would be pointless if a minimum, adequate market-guided
production activity of a dynamic and competitive nature is not kept.