GRANADA WORKSHOP REPORT 4
Agricultural Policy Analysis Unit, MAFF, Warsaw
Abstract
This paper is an overview of the most important issues which arise
from integration of the new member states in respect of the Less Favoured
Areas (LFA). It was judged that problem of the LFA in the EU acceding countries
(EUAC) is important as it will relate to a large area estimated to be between
one quarter and half a million of square kilometres depending on how many
countries will accede the EU. There are considerable differences between
the EUAC both with regard to share of the LFAs in total farmland and in
the way that national agricultural policies treat these areas. Future development
of the LFA largely depends on a way in which the EUAC will direct subsidies
to agriculture. Generally, all production de-coupled subsidies will help
to develop LFA with low-intensity farming while production-coupled payments
could reverse this welcomed trend.
Less Favoured Areas (LFA) and their potential importance in the EU
acceding countries (EUAC)
The LFA are only vaguely defined as pointed out at the beginning of
Brouwer et al. paper presented at the Nafplio conference. Although, it
is indisputable that the LFA consists of mountains, moorlands, wetlands,
heaths and rough pastures. Interestingly, areas which are perceived as
the LFA in France may come under the LFA in Spain. For example the mountain-originated
LFA starts in France from 600 m., in Germany from 800 m. and in Spain from
1000 m. above the sea level; also different values of slope (from 20% in
most countries to 25% in Portugal) qualify given area as the LFA.
Taking into account, that criteria for counting a given area as the
LFA differ across the EU member states, it is difficult at this point to
quantify how much of the farmland in the EUAC belongs to the LFA. Taking
into account only the altitude criteria, the differences may be significant.
For example if all the areas above 500 m. in Poland were counted as the
LFA, 3.1% of area of Poland would go under the LFA regulation. But if farmland
above 1000 m. was counted as the LFA, only 0.2% of Poland would qualify
as the LFA. Taking into account that total area of Poland is about 323
thousand of square kilometres, the difference is significant and reaching
nearly 1000 km2 (100 000 ha). It can be expected that other criteria give
similar differences and that cumulative effect can be large. Because the
criteria are not specified for each EUAC yet, the problem of how much of
the EUAC farmland can be counted as the LFA can not be solved at this point
by summing up the LFA in each country.
However, for many reasons (for example budgetary implications) it is
important to have a vague idea of how large the LFA can be expected in
the EUAC. It is estimated that the LFA in the European Union represent
about 56% of total farmland. Assuming that there is no significant reason
to expect that this share is much different in the EUAC, an estimate of
the LFA in the EUAC can be calculated. If to the EUAC are counted all ten
EUAC countries, than the LFA would be about a half million km2. But if
to the EUAC count only these countries which are most advanced in integration
process (Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovenia - EUAC-4) the LFA
would be around a quarter of a million km2.
Based on this simplistic but useful calculation, it can be concluded,
that the LFA is an important issue for integration of the new member states
and should be much better researched than it is at the moment.
Current status of the LFA in the EUAC
There are considerable differences between the EUAC both with regard
to share of the LFAs in total farmland and in the way that national agricultural
policies treats these areas. This paragraph gives a short overview of the
LFA problem in Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovenia.
Czech Republic has farm structure comparable with the UK; the average
farm size is 57 ha (in statistics only farms larger than 1 ha are counted),
share of agriculture in GDP is around 7.0% and employment in agriculture
reaches about 8.0% of total working population. From this figures it appears
that labour productivity in agriculture is at the national average level.
There are some measures used in Czech Republic to support the LFA. The
support covers about 35% to 50% of the farmland. Subsidies are granted
for conservation of grassland and a sort of set-accede scheme. Farmers
in LFA were paid to switch from cereal production to grassland. Large such
action was taken in 1994 when 200 mil KC (4 mil UD$) was spent to establish
grassland on previously arable area. In 1995 the expenses were lower as
they were mainly aimed at conservation of the newly created and previously
existing grasslands. There is also a large programme implement for landscape
management; in 1994 about 11 mil US$ was spent for it and in 1995 this
sum was two and a half times higher. Considerable amount of money is also
spent for afforestation: 0.3 mil US$ in 1994 and 0.65 mil US$ in 1995.
Hungarian agriculture has about 9% share in GDP and employs 15% of the
Hungarian work force. Labour productivity is considerably below the national
average. Agricultural policy in Hungary is not directed to assist the LFA
in a special way. Subsidies to agriculture are spent mostly for market
intervention and almost none for LFA (see the OECD report).
Share of Polish agriculture in GDP is about 6% and employs about 25%
of work force. From these numbers it is clear, that labour productivity
is about one fourth of the national average. This is especially evident
in areas which can be defined as LFA. Average farm size is about 7 ha (in
statistics only farms larger than 1 ha are counted).
With respect to LFA, the situation is similar to Hungarian; supporting
market intervention and farmers pension schemes gets priority. However
government provides some assistance for farmers who decided to derive income
outside the agriculture. The assistance covers transfers of know-how and
information on existing business opportunities outside the agriculture.
The assistance is not tied to the LFA, but for economic reasons farmers
use the government help in areas which could be defined as LFA. Economic
forces (quite unfavourable especially for small farmers) and government
support have already pushed some farmers out of agriculture. These exits
are recorded in statistics and demonstrate in falling share of farmers
in rural population.
Problem of LFA in Slovenia is very important and the government devotes
considerable support for them. There are about 20 regional projects to
create so called 'vine roads'. Under these programmes most of the money
are spent to create and improve tourist facilities and in this way to provide
an alternative (or supplementary) income for farmers. These 20 programmes
are run in highlands, mountains and high altitude regions.
Future development and perspectives
Future development of the LFA in a long run is determined by the accession
to the European Union. If prices levels in the EUAC are aligned to the
EU levels, there is a danger of encouraging significantly higher agricultural
production. The implication would be that also farmers in LFA would have
an incentive to raise production. Thus, the positive trends of falling
production in LFA or getting less intensive may be reversed. Therefore
it is argued in line with the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) reforms
and World Trade Organisation (WTO) principles, that money which are spent
on helping farmers (including these who farm in LFA) to raise their income,
should be granted in a production de-coupled way. As stated by many authors
(for example Tangermann and Josling, Buckwell) WTO constraints are a serious
problem if unreformed CAP would be applied to the EUAC. Production would
increase to such extent, that enlarged Union would not be able to meet
WTO commitments and would have to bear enormous budget costs (Tangermann
and Josling). The qualitative analysis of suggests that, potentially, supply
control can be a solution. But it is a problematic measure. After having
set prices, setting the level of supply would freeze two important economic
variables which for many reasons is not desirable.
It is also difficult to implement supply control for practical reasons.
Production of only a few products in the EU is controlled. Once the EUAC
join the European Union, new supply controls cannot apply only to selected
country but it will have to operate for the whole Union. Whether application
of supply controls for the whole Union would be politically acceptable
is a debatable issue. But perhaps even more difficult is the problem of
how to control supply using administrative measures. It is not clear if
supply control should restrain the number of animals on the farm or the
sale of these animals. Should the restrictions be calculated on the basis
of output, land or even the capacity of cowsheds? There are no easy answers
and it is not an accident that production quotas which operate within the
CAP relate only to sugar-beet and milk. These products have features which
help supply control; sugar-beet is practically useless if unprocessed,
and milk is perishable. Supply control for other products (which can be
relatively easy processed) can for example induce dual markets. The example
of the centrally planned economy shows that, if supply control led to a
large imbalance in the official markets, alternative markets emerge to
compensate for this effect and no administrative bans on these markets
can stop people trading outside the official system. In addition, even
if there would be a way of effective supply control, agricultural production
in some EUAC (Poland, Slovenia) is characterised by a low number of animals
per farm and it would be difficult and costly to control supply. Certainly,
some small meat processors would probably willingly take the risk of illegal
trade in return for some extra income. Clearly, introduction of supply
control would not be easy, but that does not mean that it cannot be introduced
at all.